Have you ever had
too much money? I have. I once had so much money, that I had no idea what to do
with all of it, so I went to my local bank to see if they would hold onto some
of it for me. You know, keep it safe until I needed it for a large purchase.
This should be a familiar sounding story for most people, yet the process by
which banking truly takes place is extremely large and complex. The story of
too much money, however, is exactly where banking starts. Banking is a result
of the law of association. Its existence is based on specialization. When
people build up a large store of wealth, they can either employ their own
resources to protect that wealth, or they can seek out those who already have
the necessary “set-up” to protect large amounts of money.
Originally,
banking took place when people paid banking institutions a fee or some kind for
protecting their stores of value. For our purposes, we will use gold as an
example of a store of value. In any scenario, an individual would bring his or
her gold to the bank and deposited it into a vault of some sort. The bank would
then charge a fee large enough to cover all costs and still make a profit while
remaining competitive. In exchange for the gold, the bank would issue units of promissory
notes that reflected the amount of the gold he had stored. This note would
state that at any time, the individual may come back and exchange the promissory
notes for the gold he had stored in the bank. By this process, promissory notes
make way for currencies. It is much easier to measure values in exchanges by
using units of promissory notes instead of deciding the value of gold. They’re
also much easier to carry around. As long as the bank kept their word, then the
notes could be exchanged for other goods and services, and the party that ended
up with the notes could return to the bank where the gold was stored and redeem
the store of value.
Banks, then, have
a very strong incentive to keep their word, and also to keep a 100% reserve
storage of all of their customers’ valuables. This strict policy of honest
banking, like any honest exchange, is kept alive by market competition. Banking
institutions that don’t keep promises would go out of business, or at least
lose business, overtime because customers would be willing to pay someone else
for better service. Many banks, however, may be incentivized to cheat on their
promissory notes by lending out a greater number of promissory notes than the
given store of value that they held. In doing this, they have both stolen from
the person whose store of wealth they promised to keep on hand, and they have
committed fraud against the person who was lent promissory notes that may not
be redeemable for the promised amount in the future.
Through the market
process, however, competing banks with competing promissory notes would
diminish the incentives to commit such crimes and inflate the supply of money. This
is because not only can customers bring their gold to other banks, but
competing banks could put rivals out of business by exposing their bad behavior
and buying up a large amount of the promissory notes that the competitor has
issued. In doing so, the competing bank could attempt to redeem said notes for
the given amount of gold. If the rival bank was, indeed, issuing more notes
than he had gold, he would be unable to give back enough gold to all of the
people that he promised, and that bank would go out of business, and
potentially be subject to the law.
Sadly, this is not
the banking system that is utilized in America today. There is not market
process to provide checks and balances to the operations of competing banks.
Banks are not subject to the will of consumers, but rather to the will of the
government and the Federal Reserve. When money is deposited into a bank today,
there is no fee that is paid for the storage. In fact, in most cases the bank
pays the customer a very small amount of interest. The money that is stored is
not kept safe in a vault with the customer’s name on it; it is loaned out to
others or used in various investment ventures. Granted, there is FDIC
insurance, which allows for a portion of an individual’s deposits to be paid
back were anything to happen to the bank, but this type of “insurance” comes
with a heavy price: Inflation. Because banks do not see the same incentives to
keep an honest store of value in the same way that they would in a free market
banking, they may engage in riskier loans and investments. When these loans are
unable to be paid at the same time as people come to redeem their deposits,
banks (theoretically) would not be able to come through on all of their
promises. Because of the Federal Reserve, banks can simply ask for an influx of
cash from the central bank in order to fulfill their short-term obligations. This
activity, coupled with the issuance of a multiplicity of promissory notes,
leads to a severe increase in the supply of money over time. This drastic
increase in money ultimately leads to inflation, and a decrease in the
purchasing power of each unit of money.
The only cure to such a disease is to allow
people to bank freely, without force or coercion from the government or the
Fed. Through the market process, competing currencies would once again emerge
with a sound store of value, providing incentives to keep customers happy and
keep dollars strong. Free the money... free the people.